The rise of blockchain-based finance has stimulated debates on the future of money, particularly in areas previously limited to academia and central bank policy circles. Stablecoins—digital assets designed to maintain par value with national currencies—have become the dominant bridge between traditional and decentralized finance. While there are a lot of people bullposting the prospect of stablecoin adoption, it may not be in the best interests of the US to promote stablecoins, because it can disrupt the USD money creation. TLDR:
To explain more thoroughly, this article dissects stablecoin dynamics from multiple angles:
In mainstream monetary theory, money creation occurs in large part through fractional-reserve banking. A simplified model illustrates how commercial banks amplify the monetary base (often denoted M0) into broader measures such as M1 and M2. If R is the required—or desired—reserve ratio, then the standard multiplier is approximately m=1/R
For instance, if banks must hold 10% of deposits as reserves, the multiplier mmm can be around 10. This means that a $1 injection into the system (e.g., via open market operations) can manifest as up to $10 in new deposits across the banking system.
In the United States, M1≈6×M0. This expansion underpins modern credit creation and is essential for financing mortgages, corporate loans, and other forms of productive capital.
Stablecoins issued on public blockchains (e.g., USDC, USDT) typically promise a 1:1 backing with fiat reserves, T-bills, or other near-cash assets. As a result, these issuers do not (officially) lend out customer deposits in the manner commercial banks do. Instead, they provide liquidity on-chain by creating digital tokens that remain fully redeemable for “true dollars.” Economically, such stablecoins resemble narrow banks: institutions holding 100% high-quality liquid assets against their deposit-like liabilities.
From a purely theoretical standpoint, the money multiplier for these stablecoin liabilities is closer to 1: unlike commercial banks, stablecoin issuers are not creating additional money when they accept $100 million in deposits and hold $100 million in T-bills. However, stablecoins can function like money if they gain widespread acceptance. As we will discuss later, the net effect on overall money supply can still be expansionary because stablecoins free up underlying funds (e.g., from U.S. Treasury auctions) that the government spends.
Obtaining a Federal Reserve Master Account is a key for stablecoin issuers, because financial institutions with such accounts enjoy many advantages:
However, granting stablecoin issuers direct access to these facilities presents two main ‘excuses’:
Traditional central banks may thus resist awarding stablecoin firms the same privileges as commercial banks, fearing a diminished capacity to influence the supply of credit and liquidity in times of crisis.
A subtle but crucial effect occurs when stablecoin issuers hold large amounts of US Treasuries or other government debt. This is the double-spend effect: the US government effectively has citizens’ capital to (re)finance spending, while stablecoin users that circulates like money.
Hence, this can at most double the effective stock of spendable dollars in circulation, even if not to the same extent as full fractional-reserve banking. From a macroeconomic perspective, stablecoins thereby facilitate an additional channel through which government borrowing enters day-to-day transactions.
Some have speculated about stablecoin issuers eventually being permitted to lend out a portion of their reserves, effectively creating money in the same way as commercial banks. This would require a robust regulatory framework akin to bank charters, FDIC insurance, and capital adequacy standards (BASAL). While some legislative proposals (e.g., the “GENIUS Act”) outline a path for stablecoin issuers to become bank-like entities, the 1:1 reserve requirement embedded in these proposals suggests no near-term shift to a fractional-reserve model.
A more radical alternative is the development of central bank digital currencies (CBDCs), where the central bank itself issues digital liabilities directly to consumers and businesses. CBDCs might combine the programmability of stablecoins with the trust of sovereign money. Yet from the perspective of commercial banks, the disintermediation risk is glaringly obvious: if the public can hold direct digital accounts at the central bank, deposits might drain from private banks, limiting their capacity to fund loans.
In an era where large stablecoin issuers (e.g., Circle, Tether) hold tens or hundreds of billions in short-term treasuries, fluctuations in stablecoin demand might have non-negligible impacts on U.S. money markets. A stablecoin “redeem wave” could force issuers to dump T-bills rapidly, pushing yields higher and potentially destabilizing short-term funding markets. On the flipside, an influx of stablecoin issuance might compress T-bill yields. This interplay highlights how stablecoins—if they reach a scale comparable to large money market funds—could leak into traditional monetary plumbing.
Stablecoins sit at the intersection of technological innovation, regulatory oversight, and long-established monetary theory. They bring programmability and ubiquitous accessibility to the concept of money, enabling new paradigms for payments and settlement. However, these advantages also toggle the delicate balances integral to current financial systems, particularly fractional-reserve lending and central bank monetary control.
In short, stablecoins might not replace commercial banks but will continue to pressure the established banking sector to innovate. As stablecoins grow, central banks and financial authorities face the challenge of reconciling global liquidity, departmental oversight, and the broader economic multipliers that rely on fractional reserves. The evolution of stablecoins—whether through stricter regulation, partial reserve approaches, or integration into a broader CBDC framework—will shape not only the future of digital payments, but potentially the trajectory of global monetary policy itself.
Ultimately, stablecoins highlight the tension between the efficiency gains of a more direct, fully reserved system and the economic growth benefits of a leveraged fractional-reserve model. Navigating this frontier will require rigorous economic analysis to see how to get the best of both sides (transaction efficiency + money creation)
This article is reprinted from [X]. All copyrights belong to the original author [@DeFi_Cheetah]. If there are objections to this reprint, please contact the Gate Learn team, and they will handle it promptly.
Liability Disclaimer: The views and opinions expressed in this article are solely those of the author and do not constitute any investment advice.
Translations of the article into other languages are done by the Gate Learn team. Unless mentioned, copying, distributing, or plagiarizing the translated articles is prohibited.
The rise of blockchain-based finance has stimulated debates on the future of money, particularly in areas previously limited to academia and central bank policy circles. Stablecoins—digital assets designed to maintain par value with national currencies—have become the dominant bridge between traditional and decentralized finance. While there are a lot of people bullposting the prospect of stablecoin adoption, it may not be in the best interests of the US to promote stablecoins, because it can disrupt the USD money creation. TLDR:
To explain more thoroughly, this article dissects stablecoin dynamics from multiple angles:
In mainstream monetary theory, money creation occurs in large part through fractional-reserve banking. A simplified model illustrates how commercial banks amplify the monetary base (often denoted M0) into broader measures such as M1 and M2. If R is the required—or desired—reserve ratio, then the standard multiplier is approximately m=1/R
For instance, if banks must hold 10% of deposits as reserves, the multiplier mmm can be around 10. This means that a $1 injection into the system (e.g., via open market operations) can manifest as up to $10 in new deposits across the banking system.
In the United States, M1≈6×M0. This expansion underpins modern credit creation and is essential for financing mortgages, corporate loans, and other forms of productive capital.
Stablecoins issued on public blockchains (e.g., USDC, USDT) typically promise a 1:1 backing with fiat reserves, T-bills, or other near-cash assets. As a result, these issuers do not (officially) lend out customer deposits in the manner commercial banks do. Instead, they provide liquidity on-chain by creating digital tokens that remain fully redeemable for “true dollars.” Economically, such stablecoins resemble narrow banks: institutions holding 100% high-quality liquid assets against their deposit-like liabilities.
From a purely theoretical standpoint, the money multiplier for these stablecoin liabilities is closer to 1: unlike commercial banks, stablecoin issuers are not creating additional money when they accept $100 million in deposits and hold $100 million in T-bills. However, stablecoins can function like money if they gain widespread acceptance. As we will discuss later, the net effect on overall money supply can still be expansionary because stablecoins free up underlying funds (e.g., from U.S. Treasury auctions) that the government spends.
Obtaining a Federal Reserve Master Account is a key for stablecoin issuers, because financial institutions with such accounts enjoy many advantages:
However, granting stablecoin issuers direct access to these facilities presents two main ‘excuses’:
Traditional central banks may thus resist awarding stablecoin firms the same privileges as commercial banks, fearing a diminished capacity to influence the supply of credit and liquidity in times of crisis.
A subtle but crucial effect occurs when stablecoin issuers hold large amounts of US Treasuries or other government debt. This is the double-spend effect: the US government effectively has citizens’ capital to (re)finance spending, while stablecoin users that circulates like money.
Hence, this can at most double the effective stock of spendable dollars in circulation, even if not to the same extent as full fractional-reserve banking. From a macroeconomic perspective, stablecoins thereby facilitate an additional channel through which government borrowing enters day-to-day transactions.
Some have speculated about stablecoin issuers eventually being permitted to lend out a portion of their reserves, effectively creating money in the same way as commercial banks. This would require a robust regulatory framework akin to bank charters, FDIC insurance, and capital adequacy standards (BASAL). While some legislative proposals (e.g., the “GENIUS Act”) outline a path for stablecoin issuers to become bank-like entities, the 1:1 reserve requirement embedded in these proposals suggests no near-term shift to a fractional-reserve model.
A more radical alternative is the development of central bank digital currencies (CBDCs), where the central bank itself issues digital liabilities directly to consumers and businesses. CBDCs might combine the programmability of stablecoins with the trust of sovereign money. Yet from the perspective of commercial banks, the disintermediation risk is glaringly obvious: if the public can hold direct digital accounts at the central bank, deposits might drain from private banks, limiting their capacity to fund loans.
In an era where large stablecoin issuers (e.g., Circle, Tether) hold tens or hundreds of billions in short-term treasuries, fluctuations in stablecoin demand might have non-negligible impacts on U.S. money markets. A stablecoin “redeem wave” could force issuers to dump T-bills rapidly, pushing yields higher and potentially destabilizing short-term funding markets. On the flipside, an influx of stablecoin issuance might compress T-bill yields. This interplay highlights how stablecoins—if they reach a scale comparable to large money market funds—could leak into traditional monetary plumbing.
Stablecoins sit at the intersection of technological innovation, regulatory oversight, and long-established monetary theory. They bring programmability and ubiquitous accessibility to the concept of money, enabling new paradigms for payments and settlement. However, these advantages also toggle the delicate balances integral to current financial systems, particularly fractional-reserve lending and central bank monetary control.
In short, stablecoins might not replace commercial banks but will continue to pressure the established banking sector to innovate. As stablecoins grow, central banks and financial authorities face the challenge of reconciling global liquidity, departmental oversight, and the broader economic multipliers that rely on fractional reserves. The evolution of stablecoins—whether through stricter regulation, partial reserve approaches, or integration into a broader CBDC framework—will shape not only the future of digital payments, but potentially the trajectory of global monetary policy itself.
Ultimately, stablecoins highlight the tension between the efficiency gains of a more direct, fully reserved system and the economic growth benefits of a leveraged fractional-reserve model. Navigating this frontier will require rigorous economic analysis to see how to get the best of both sides (transaction efficiency + money creation)
This article is reprinted from [X]. All copyrights belong to the original author [@DeFi_Cheetah]. If there are objections to this reprint, please contact the Gate Learn team, and they will handle it promptly.
Liability Disclaimer: The views and opinions expressed in this article are solely those of the author and do not constitute any investment advice.
Translations of the article into other languages are done by the Gate Learn team. Unless mentioned, copying, distributing, or plagiarizing the translated articles is prohibited.